/usr/share/doc/anarchism/html/secC3.html is in anarchism 14.0-4.
This file is owned by root:root, with mode 0o644.
The actual contents of the file can be viewed below.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 111 112 113 114 115 116 117 118 119 120 121 122 123 124 125 126 127 128 129 130 131 132 133 134 135 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 146 147 148 149 150 151 152 153 154 155 156 157 158 159 160 161 162 163 164 165 166 167 168 169 170 171 172 173 174 175 176 177 178 179 180 181 182 183 184 185 186 187 188 189 190 191 192 193 194 195 196 197 198 199 200 201 202 203 204 205 206 207 208 209 210 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 219 220 221 222 223 224 225 226 227 228 229 230 231 232 233 234 235 236 237 238 239 240 241 242 243 244 245 246 247 248 249 250 251 252 253 254 255 256 257 258 259 260 261 262 263 264 265 266 267 268 269 270 271 272 273 274 275 276 277 278 279 280 281 282 283 284 285 286 287 288 289 290 291 292 293 294 295 296 297 298 299 300 301 302 303 304 305 306 307 308 309 310 311 312 313 314 315 316 317 318 319 320 321 322 323 324 325 326 327 | <html>
<head>
<title> C.3 What determines the distribution between labour and capital?</title>
</head>
<body>
<h1>C.3 What determines the distribution between labour and capital?</h1>
<p>
In short, class struggle determines the distribution of income between
classes (As Proudhon put it, the expression <i>"the relations of profits
to wages"</i> means <i>"the war between labour and capital."</i> [<b>System of Economical
Contradictions</b>, p. 130]). This, in turn, is dependent on the balance of
power within any given economy at any given time.
</p><p>
Given our analysis of the source of surplus value in
<a href="secC2.html#secc22">section C.2.2</a>, this
should come as no surprise. Given the central role of labour in creating
both goods (things with value) and surplus value, production prices
determine market prices. This means that market prices are governed,
however indirectly, by what goes on in production. In any company, wages
determine a large percentage of the production costs. Looking at other
costs (such as raw materials), again wages play a large role in determining
their price. Obviously the division of a commodity's price into costs and
profits is not a fixed ratio, which mean that prices are the result of
complex interactions of wage levels and productivity. Within the limits
of a given situation, the class struggle between employers and employees
over wages, working conditions and benefits determines the degree of
exploitation within a society and so the distribution of income, i.e.
the relative amount of money which goes to labour (i.e. wages) and
capital (surplus value).
</p><p>
To quote libertarian socialist Cornelius Castoriadis:
</p><p><blockquote><i>
"Far from being completely dominated by the will of the capitalist
and forced to increase indefinitely the yield of labour, production
is determined just as much by the workers' individual and collective
resistance to such increases. The extraction of 'use value form
labour power' is not a technical operation; it is a process of bitter
struggle in which half the time, so to speak, the capitalists turn
out to be losers.
</p><p>
"The same thing holds true for living standards, i.e., real wage
levels. From its beginnings, the working class has fought to reduce
the length of the workday and to raise wage levels. It is this
struggle that has determined how these levels have risen and
fallen over the years . . .
</p><p>
"Neither the actual labour rendered during an hour of labour time
nor the wage received in exchange for this work can be determined by
any kind of 'objective' law, norm, or calculation . . . What we are
saying does not mean that specifically economic or even 'objective'
factors play no real in determining wage levels. Quite the contrary.
At any given instant, the class struggle comes into play only within
a given economic -- and, more generally, objective -- framework,
and it acts not only directly but also through the intermediary of a
series of partial 'economic mechanisms.' To give only one example
among thousands, an economic victory for workers in one sector has
a ripple effect on overall wage levels, not only because it can
encourage other workers to be more combative, but also because
sectors with lower wage levels will experience greater difficulties
recruiting manpower. None of these mechanisms, however, can
effectively act on its own and have its own significance if taken
separately from the class struggle. And the economic context itself
is always gradually affected one way or another by this struggle."</i>
[<b>Political and Social Writings</b>, vol. 2, p. 248]
</blockquote></p><p>
The essential point is that the extraction of surplus value from
workers is not a simple technical operation, as implied by the
neo-classical perspective (and, ironically, classical Marxism as
Castoriadis explains in his classic work <i>"Modern Capitalism and
Revolution"</i> [<b>Op. Cit.</b>, pp. 226-343]). As noted previously, unlike
the extraction of so many joules from a ton of coal, extracting
surplus value ("use value") from labour power involves conflict
between people, between classes. Labour power is unlike all other
commodities - it is and remains inseparably embodied in human beings.
This means that the division of profits and wages in a company and
in the economy as a whole is dependent upon and modified by the
actions of workers (and capitalists), both as individuals and as
a class. It is this struggle which, ultimately, drives the
capitalist economy, it is this conflict between the human and
commodity aspects of labour power that ultimately brings capitalism
into repeated crisis (see <a href="secC7.html">section C.7</a>).
</p><p>
From this perspective, the neo-classical argument that a factor in
production (labour, capital or land) receives an income share that
indicates its productive power "at the margin" is false. Rather,
it is a question of power -- and the willingness to use it. As
Christopher Eaton Gunn points out, the neo-classical argument
<i>"take[s] no account of power -- of politics, conflict, and
bargaining -- as more likely indicators of relative shares of
income in the real world."</i> [<b>Workers' Self-Management in the
United States</b>, p. 185] Ultimately, working class struggle is an
<i>"indispensable means of raising their standard of living or defending
their attained advantages against the concerted measures of the
employers."</i> It is <i>"not only a means for the defence of immediate
economic interests, it is also a continuous schooling for their
powers of resistance, showing them every day that every last
right has to be won by unceasing struggle against the existing
system."</i> [Rocker, <b>Anarcho-Syndicalism</b>, p. 78]
</p><p>
If the power of labour is increasing, its share in income will tend
to increase and, obviously, if the power of labour decreased it would
fall. And the history of the post-war economy supports such an analysis,
with labour in the advanced countries share of income falling from 68%
in the 1970s to 65.1% in 1995 (in the EU, it fell from 69.2% to 62%).
In the USA, labour's share of income in the manufacturing sector fell
from 74.8% to 70.6% over the 1979-89 period, reversing the rise in
labour's share that occurred over the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s. The
reversal in labour's share occurred at the same time as labour's power
was undercut by right-wing governments who have pursued business
friendly "free market" policies to combat "inflation" (an euphemism
for working class militancy and resistance) by undermining working
class power and organisation by generating high unemployment.
</p><p>
Thus, for many anarchists, the relative power between labour and capital
determines the distribution of income between them. In periods of full
employment or growing workplace organisation and solidarity, workers
wages will tend to rise faster. In periods where there is high
unemployment and weaker unions and less direct action, labour's share
will fall. From this analysis anarchists support collective organisation
and action in order to increase the power of labour and ensure we
receive more of the value we produce.
</p><p>
The neo-classical notion that rising productivity allows for increasing
wages is one that has suffered numerous shocks since the early 1970s.
Usually wage increases lag behind productivity. For example, during
Thatcher's reign of freer markets, productivity rose by 4.2%, 1.4% higher
than the increase in real earnings between 1980-88. Under Reagan,
productivity increased by 3.3%, accompanied by a fall of 0.8% in real
earnings. Remember, though, these are averages and hide the actual
increases in pay differentials between workers and managers. To take
one example, the real wages for employed single men between 1978 and
1984 in the UK rose by 1.8% for the bottom 10% of that group, for the
highest 10%, it was a massive 18.4%. The average rise (10.1%) hides
the vast differences between top and bottom. In addition, these figures
ignore the starting point of these rises -- the often massive differences
in wages between employees (compare the earnings of the CEO of McDonalds
and one of its cleaners). In other words, 2.8% of nearly nothing is
still nearly nothing!
</p><p>
Looking at the USA again, we find that workers who are paid by the
hour (the majority of employees) saw their average pay peak in 1973.
Since then, it had declined substantially and stood at its mid-1960s
level in 1992. For over 80 per cent of the US workforce (production
and non-supervisory workers), real wages have fallen by 19.2 per cent
for weekly earnings and 13.4 per cent for hourly earnings between 1973
and 1994. Productivity had risen by 23.2 per cent. Combined with this
drop in real wages in the USA, we have seen an increase in hours
worked. In order to maintain their current standard of living, working
class people have turned to both debt and longer working hours.
Since 1979, the annual hours worked by middle-income families rose
from 3 020 to 3 206 in 1989, 3 287 in 1996 and 3 335 in 1997. In
Mexico we find a similar process. Between 1980 and 1992,
productivity rose by 48 per cent while salaries (adjusted for
inflation) fell by 21 per cent.
</p><p>
Between 1989 to 1997, productivity increased by 9.7% in the USA while
median compensation decreased by 4.2%. In addition, median family
working hours grew by 4% (or three weeks of full-time work) while its
income increased by only 0.6 % (in other words, increases in working
hours helped to create this slight growth). If the wages of workers
were related to their productivity, as argued by neo-classical economics,
you would expect wages to increase as productivity rose, rather than
fall. However, if wages are related to economic power, then this fall
is to be expected. This explains the desire for "flexible" labour
markets, where workers' bargaining power is eroded and so more
income can go to profits rather than wages.
</p><p>
It is amazing how far the US in 2005, the paradigm for neo-liberalism, is
from the predictions of neo-classical economic textbooks. Since the 1970s,
there has only been one period of sustained good times for working people,
the late 1990s. Before and after this period, there has been wage stagnation
(between 2000 and 2004, for example, the real median family income <b>fell</b>
by 3%). While the real income of households in the lowest fifth grew by
6.1% between 1979 and 2000, the top fifth saw an increase of 70% and the
average income of the top 1% grew by 184%. This rising inequality was
fuelled by the expansion of income from capital and an increased
concentration of capital income in the top 1% (who received 57.5% of all
capital income in 2003, compared to 37.8% in 1979). This reflected the
increased share of income flowing to corporate profits (profits rates
in 2005 were the highest in 36 years). If the pre-tax return to capital
had remained at its 1979 level, then hourly compensation would have been
5% higher. In 2005 dollars, this represents an annual transfer of $235
billion from labour to capital. [Lawrence Mishel, Jered Bernstein, and Sylvia Allegretto,
<b>The State of Working America 2006/7</b>, pp. 2-3]
</p><p>
Labour's share of income in the corporate sector fell from 82.1% in 179
to 81.1% in 1989, and then to 79.1% in 2005. However, this fall is even
worse for labour as labour income <i>"includes the pay of Chief Executive
Officers (CEOs), thereby overstating the income share going to 'workers'
and understating 'profits,' since the bonuses and stock options given
CEOs are more akin to profits than wages"</i> and so <i>"some of the profits
are showing up in CEO paychecks and are counted as worker pay."</i> [<b>Op. Cit.</b>,
p. 83 and p. 84]
</p><p>
Unsurprisingly, there has been a <i>"stunning disconnect between the rapid
productivity growth and pay growth,"</i> along with a <i>"tremendous widening
of the wage gap between those at the top of the wage scale, particularly
corporate chief executive officers [CEO], and other wage earners."</i> Between
1979 and 1995, wages <i>"were stagnant or fell for the bottom 60% of wage
earners"</i> and grew by 5% for the 80th percentile. Between 1992 and 2005,
saw median CEO pay rise by 186.2% while the media worker saw only a 7.2%
rise in their wages. Wealth inequality was even worse, with the wealth share
of the bottom 80% shrinking by 3.8 percentage points (which was gained by
the top 5% of households). Using the official standard of poverty, 11.3%
of Americans were in poverty in 2000, rising to 12.7% in 2004 (<i>"This is
the first time that poverty rose through each of the first three years
of a recovery"</i>). However, the official poverty line is hopelessly out
of date (for a family of four it was 48% of median family income in
1960, in 2006 it is 29%). Using a threshold of twice the official value
sees an increase in poverty from 29.3% to 31.2% [<b>Op. Cit.</b>, p. 4, p. 5, p. 7,
p. 9 and p. 11]
</p><p>
Of course, it will be argued that only in a perfectly competitive market
(or, more realistically, a truly "free" one) will wages increase in-line
with productivity. However, you would expect that a regime of <b>freer</b>
markets would make things better, not worse. This has not happened. The
neo-classical argument that unions, struggling over wages and working
conditions will harm workers in the "long run" has been dramatically refuted
since the 1970s -- the decline of the labour movement in the USA has been
marked by falling wages, not rising ones, for example. Despite of rising
productivity, wealth has <b>not</b> "trickled down" -- rather it has flooded up
(a situation only surprising to those who believe economic textbooks or
what politicians say). In fact, between 1947 and 1973, the median family
income rose by 103.9% while productivity rose by 103.7% and so wages and
productivity went hand-in-hand. Since the mid-1970s this close mapping
broke down. From 1973 to 2005, productivity rose by 75.5% while income
increased by a mere 21.8%, less than one-third the rate of productivity
(from 2000 to 2004, productivity rose by 14% while family income fell by
2.9%). This wedge is the source of rising inequality, with the upper
classes claiming most of the income growth. [<b>Op. Cit.</b>, p. 46]
</p><p>
All of which refutes those apologists for capitalism who cite the
empirical fact that, in a modern capitalist economy, a large majority
of all income goes to "labour," with profit, interest and rent adding
up to something under twenty percent of the total. Of course, even if
surplus value were less than 20% of a workers' output, this does not change
its exploitative nature (just as, for the capitalist apologist, taxation
does not stop being "theft" just because it is around 10% of all income).
However, this value for profit, interest and rent is based on a statistical
sleight-of-hand, as "worker" is defined as including everyone who has
a salary in a company, including managers and CEOs. The large incomes
which many managers and all CEOs receive would, of course, ensure that a
large majority of all income does go to "labour." Thus this "fact" ignores
the role of most managers as de facto capitalists and their income represents
a slice of surplus value rather than wages. This sleight-of-hand also
obscures the results of this distribution for while the 70% of "labour"
income goes into many hands, the 20% representing surplus value goes into
the hands of a few. So even if we ignore the issue of CEO "wages", the fact
is that a substantial amount of money is going into the hands of a small
minority which will, obviously, skew income, wealth and economic power
away from the vast majority.
</p><p>
To get a better picture of the nature of exploitation within modern capitalism
we have to compare workers wages to their productivity. According to the
World Bank, in 1966, US manufacturing wages were equal to 46% of the
value-added in production (value-added is the difference between selling
price and the costs of raw materials and other inputs to the production
process). In 1990, that figure had fallen to 36% and by 1993, to 35%. Figures
from the 1992 Economic Census of the US Census Bureau indicate it had reached
19.76% (39.24% if we take the <b>total</b> payroll which includes managers and so
on). In the US construction industry, wages were 35.4% of value added in 1992
(with total payroll, 50.18%). Therefore the argument that because a large
percentage of income goes to "labour" capitalism is fine hides the realities
of that system and the exploitation its hierarchical nature creates.
</p><p>
Overall, since the 1970s working class America has seen stagnating income,
rising working hours and falling social (i.e. income-class) mobility while,
at the same time, productivity has been rising and inequality soaring.
While this may come as a surprise (or be considered a paradox by capitalist
economics, a paradox usually to be justified and rationalised id acknowledged
at all) anarchists consider this to be a striking confirmation of their
analysis. Unsurprisingly, in a hierarchical system those at the top do
better than those at the bottom. The system is set up so that the majority
enrich the minority. That is way anarchists argue that workplace organisation
and resistance is essential to maintain -- and even increase -- labour's
income. For if the share of income between labour and capital depends on
their relative power -- and it does -- then only the actions of workers
themselves can improve their situation and determine the distribution of
the value they create.
</p><p>
This analysis obviously applied <b>within</b> classes as well. At any time, there
is a given amount of unpaid labour in circulation in the form of goods or
services representing more added value than workers were paid for. This given
sum of unpaid labour (surplus value) represents a total over which the
different capitalists, landlords and bankers fight over. Each company tries
to maximise its share of that total, and if a company does realise an
above-average share, it means that some other companies receive less than
average.
</p><p>
The key to distribution within the capitalist class is, as between that
class and the working class, power. Looking at what is normally, although
somewhat inaccurately, called monopoly this is obvious. The larger the
company with respect to its market, the more likely it is to obtain a
larger share of the available surplus, for reasons discussed later (see
<a href="secC5.html">section C.5</a>). While this represents a distribution of surplus value
<b>between</b> capitalists based on market power, the important thing to note
here is that while companies compete on the market to realise their share
of the total surplus (unpaid labour) the <b>source</b> of these profits does
not lie in the market, but in production. One cannot buy what does not
exist and if one gains, another loses.
</p><p>
Market power also plays a key role in producing inflation, which has its roots
in the ability of firms to pass cost increases to consumers in the form of
higher prices. This represents a distribution of income from lenders to
borrowers, i.e. from finance capital to industrial capital and labour to
capital (as capital "borrows" labour, i.e. the workers are paid <b>after</b>
they have produced goods for their bosses). How able capitalists are to
pass on costs to the general population depends on how able they are to
withstand competition from other companies, i.e. how much they dominate
their market and can act as a price setter. Of course, inflation is not the
only possible outcome of rising costs (such as wage rises). It is always
possible to reduce profits or increase the productivity of labour (i.e.
increase the rate of exploitation). The former is rarely raised as a
possibility, as the underlying assumption seems to be that profits are
sacrosanct, and the latter is dependent, of course, on the balance of
forces within the economy.
</p><p>
In the next section, we discuss why capitalism is marked by big business
and what this concentrated market power means to the capitalist economy.
</p>
</body>
</html>
|